Negative interest on excess reserves is an instrument of unconventional monetary policy applied by central banks to encourage lending by making it costly for commercial banks to hold their excess reserves at central banks so they will lend more readily to the private sector. Such policy is usually associated with very slow economic growth, deflation, and deleverage.
During economic downturns, central banks often lower interest rates to stimulate growth. Until recently, it was thought that rates couldn't go below zero because people would hold on to cash instead of paying a fee to deposit it. It turns out this was not quite right. Central banks in Europe and in Japan have demonstrated rates can go negative, and several have pushed them in that direction for the same reason they lowered them to zero in the first placeâ"to provide stimulus and, where inflation is below target, to raise the inflation rate. The notion is that negative rates will provide even more incentive for commercial banks to make loans. What might have looked like a project not worth funding even in a low-interest-rate environment might now look attractive if the alternative is being charged to store money at the central bank or holding lots of cash.
Examples
Europe
The European Central Bank and central banks of other European countries, such as Sweden, Switzerland, and Denmark, have paid negative interest on excess reservesâ"in effect taxing banks for exceeding their reserve requirementsâ"as an expansionary monetary policy measure.
Negative rates in Europe have been controversial. Ambrose Evans-Pritchard of the London Telegraph has described them as a "calamitous misadventure." Economists for the European Central Bank, not surprisingly, disagree. They argue that across the euro area, loans from banks to corporations have become less expensive since negative rates were adopted.
Japan
In January 2016, the Bank of Japan followed other European central banks and lowered its interest rates below zero, after several years of keeping them at the lower end of the positive range. The existing balances will keep on yielding a rate of 0.1 percent; the reserves that banks are required to keep at the BOJ will have a rate of zero percent, and a rate of minus 0.1 percent will be applied to any other reserves.
U.S.
The staff of the U.S. Federal Reserve prepared a memo for the Federal Open Market Committee in August 2010 evaluating the interest rate that the Fed paid on bank reserves to zero or below. The staff was lukewarm on the idea, and it was never adopted in the U.S. Former Fed Chair Ben Bernanke has argued that "negative rates appear to have both modest benefits and manageable costs" and "modestly negative" interest rates should be an option for the Fed to consider if it ever again confront a very weak economy at a time when short-term interest rates already have been cut to zero.
See also
- Excess reserves
- Forward guidance
- IOER â" interest on excess reserves
- Negative interest rate
- Zero interest rate policy (ZIRP)
References
External links
- Why has the ECB introduced a negative interest rate? (European Central Bank, June, 2014)
- "The ECB's Negative Interest Rate: The Fed May Be Forced To Follow Its Lead" (former Dallas Federal Reserve President Bob McTeer, Forbes, June 5, 2014)
- "Will the European Central Bankâs negative interest rate be an economic positive?" (Simone Pathe, PBS Newshour, June 9, 2014)
- "Japan adopts negative interest rates in surprise move". BBC. 29 January 2016. Retrieved 29 January 2016.Â